• ⚠️ UK Access Block Notice: Beginning July 1, 2025, this site will no longer be accessible from the United Kingdom. This is a voluntary decision made by the site's administrators. We were not forced or ordered to implement this block.

DarkRange55

DarkRange55

We are now gods but for the wisdom
Oct 15, 2023
2,059
Brazil's hyperinflation of the 1980s and early 1990s is one of the most studied modern inflationary crises, and it provides a particularly revealing case for assessing gold's role as a store of value. Unlike Weimar Germany or Zimbabwe, where gold or foreign exchange clearly outshone the collapsing local currency, Brazil shows that gold, while helpful in shielding purchasing power against the cruzeiro's debasement, often lagged behind other avenues of protection — especially access to U.S. dollars, international bonds, and real estate. This makes Brazil a critical counterexample to the idea that gold is always the supreme hedge in hyperinflationary conditions.

During the late 1970s, Brazil was already struggling with inflation running at 40–50% per year, but by the mid-1980s it had escalated to full-blown hyperinflation. According to IMF and World Bank data, annual inflation surpassed 1,000% several times, peaking at over 2,400% in 1993. Ordinary Brazilians saw their life savings destroyed as the currency was redenominated repeatedly: from the cruzeiro (in use until 1986) to the cruzado (1986), back to the cruzeiro (1989), then to the cruzeiro novo (1993), and finally to the real in 1994 under the Plano Real reforms. Prices often doubled within weeks, and the monetary system lost credibility almost entirely.

In such an environment, it might be assumed that gold was the natural and unbeatable hedge. Indeed, in local cruzeiro terms, gold prices skyrocketed. A household that had kept an ounce of gold under the mattress did far better than one that trusted the banking system. Yet when returns are measured more carefully — relative to inflation, foreign assets, and later stabilization — the picture becomes more complex. Gold was protective, but it was not the best-performing asset class, either for short-term survival or for long-term wealth preservation.

One reason is that foreign currencies outperformed gold in practical utility. The U.S. dollar became the real yardstick of value in Brazil. Merchants, landlords, and even professionals often preferred payment in dollars rather than cruzeiros, and for good reason: the dollar held steady while the local currency evaporated. Gold, by contrast, was not nearly as liquid in day-to-day life. While families who held jewelry or coins could sell them at a premium to survive, the transaction costs were high, spreads were wide, and the logistics were cumbersome compared to simply pricing goods and wages in U.S. dollars. In practice, the dollar displaced gold as the medium of account for survival.

Beyond daily life, real estate in Brazil also proved a far more powerful anchor than gold. Urban property values rose rapidly, especially in São Paulo and Rio de Janeiro, as citizens sought to park their wealth in tangible assets that could generate rental income and adjust with inflation. Real estate had the dual advantage of being a productive asset and being denominated in dollar-linked rents. While gold sat inert, apartments and commercial properties not only retained value but often outpaced inflation through income streams. Scholarly studies of Brazil's property market during this era note that even in times of monetary chaos, real estate provided relative stability and eventual upside once the Plano Real restored confidence.

Equities, too, eventually surpassed gold by a wide margin. The Brazilian stock market, represented by the Bovespa Index (now Ibovespa), was a volatile and treacherous place in the midst of hyperinflation. Many companies failed, and equity holders saw wild swings in value. Yet once inflation was tamed in 1994 and the economy stabilized, equities entered one of the strongest bull runs of the late 20th century. Investors who had managed to hold diversified positions in the equity market or who re-entered after stabilization vastly outperformed those who held only gold. An ounce of gold in 1994 bought security; a diversified equity portfolio bought compounding growth that left gold far behind by the 2000s.

Perhaps the most striking evidence comes from comparisons of gold to international assets. Studies on Brazilian hyperinflation show that investors who managed to move wealth offshore into U.S. Treasury bonds, equities, or even simple dollar deposits were the real winners. These assets not only preserved purchasing power but also delivered positive real returns once converted back after stabilization. Gold, while strong in nominal terms, simply preserved value; it did not multiply it. The difference is crucial: gold helped people survive, but international diversification allowed them to thrive.

The IMF's post-mortems on the Plano Real underscore this point. Brazil's stabilization succeeded by anchoring expectations to the dollar and introducing a credible fiscal and monetary framework. Investors who were positioned in dollar-linked or dollar-denominated assets saw enormous gains as confidence returned. Gold's role faded, because its utility was tied to fear of collapse. Once the collapse ended, gold stagnated, while equities and bonds surged.

The Brazilian case also highlights the problem of transaction costs in gold markets during hyperinflation. Premiums on coins and jewelry widened to 20–30%, meaning that a family selling gold to pay for groceries or rent received far less than the quoted market price. Meanwhile, those holding U.S. dollars faced far narrower spreads, making their wealth more liquid and flexible. For survival, liquidity matters as much as value preservation, and on this front gold was a weaker tool than hard currency.

It is also worth noting that in Brazil, as in many other hyperinflations, social networks and political access determined outcomes more than raw asset choices. Those with the ability to transfer capital abroad, buy foreign assets, or secure real estate titles were able to preserve and build wealth. Gold could help the middle class or rural households weather the storm, but the elites who diversified internationally left the crisis in far stronger positions. This is an important caveat to any simple story of gold as the universal protector.

From a purely financial standpoint, long-run return comparisons are sobering. While exact series are difficult to reconstruct because of currency redenominations, scholars like Hanke and Krus, along with Brazilian economic historians, show that a dollar held in U.S. equities or bonds from 1980 to 2000 vastly outperformed an ounce of gold held in São Paulo. Gold preserved relative domestic wealth, but global diversification provided real compounding. Investors who simply sat on gold in Brazil missed the explosive upside that followed stabilization.

This makes Brazil an especially important teaching case. It shows that gold should not be mistaken for a panacea. Gold's volatility, its lack of yield, and its limited liquidity in everyday life mean that it often underperforms assets that are productive, income-generating, or internationally liquid. In Brazil, it was not the best hedge; it was simply the floor that prevented total collapse. For those who wanted to climb above the floor, equities, real estate, and foreign assets were superior.

Brazil's hyperinflation thus illustrates the difference between preservation and growth. Gold preserved value relative to a collapsing currency; it did not deliver growth beyond that. Real estate and equities not only preserved but ultimately multiplied wealth. Foreign assets provided the greatest shield of all, combining stability with growth. In this sense, Brazil's experience is a powerful counterweight to gold enthusiasts who cite hyperinflation as an automatic case for gold supremacy.

Part II · Section 2B (¶76–100) — Russia, Yugoslavia, Synthesis

Russia's transition from communism to capitalism in the early 1990s was one of the most chaotic economic experiments of the modern era. Following the collapse of the Soviet Union in 1991, inflation spiraled out of control. By 1992, annual inflation had reached nearly 2,500%, with monthly inflation rates regularly exceeding 50%. The ruble collapsed, wiping out the savings of ordinary citizens. Gold in ruble terms surged, offering protection against the collapse of fiat money. Families who had held gold coins or jewelry saw their purchasing power survive in ways unimaginable for those who trusted the ruble. Yet, as in Brazil, gold was not the top-performing hedge.

The real winner in Russia was the U.S. dollar. As trust in the ruble evaporated, Russians turned overwhelmingly to hard currency. "Dollarization" became widespread: wages were negotiated in dollars, rents were priced in dollars, and consumer goods were quoted in dollars. Supermarkets and landlords alike simply ignored the ruble. Gold, while valuable, was less liquid and harder to use in daily transactions. The dollar was the functional currency of survival. This difference mattered enormously: gold could store value, but only the dollar could function as money in practice.

Foreign bonds and equities also proved stronger long-term hedges than gold. Russians who managed to move capital into U.S. Treasuries or global equities not only preserved their wealth but enjoyed compounding returns as the 1990s bull market roared ahead in the West. Gold, by contrast, stagnated after the initial ruble collapse. It had done its job as insurance, but once stabilization came under Yeltsin and later Putin, it failed to generate growth. Again, the contrast was clear: gold protected against collapse but did not participate in recovery.

Domestic equities in Russia were a different story. In the short run, they were catastrophic, collapsing along with the broader economy. But by the early 2000s, Russian equities became one of the best-performing markets in the world, compounding wealth for investors who held on. Gold could not match that rebound. As in Brazil, the lesson was that productive assets ultimately outperformed gold once inflation was tamed.

Yugoslavia's hyperinflation in 1992–1994 offers an even starker view of gold's limitations. With the country disintegrating under sanctions and civil war, inflation reached 313 million percent per monthin January 1994, according to Hanke and Krus. Prices doubled every 1.4 days, and the dinar became worthless almost overnight. In this environment, one might expect gold to reign supreme. In reality, the German Deutsche Mark became the dominant store of value.

The Deutsche Mark was not just a hedge; it was the effective money of daily life. Wages, rents, and prices were quoted in marks, not dinars. Gold preserved wealth for those who held it, but it was not liquid. A family with Deutsche Marks could buy food and pay rent; a family with gold had to find a buyer, endure wide bid-ask spreads, and convert into marks before transacting. Gold was insurance, but the mark was survival.

Real estate also played a key role in Yugoslavia. Properties in Belgrade or other major cities were increasingly priced in Deutsche Marks, and rents were indexed accordingly. Real estate, like in Brazil, provided both a store of value and a productive stream of income. Gold could not match this. The hierarchy in Yugoslavia was clear: foreign currency first, real estate second, gold third.

These three cases — Brazil, Russia, and Yugoslavia — show the limits of gold in hyperinflationary environments. Gold certainly outperforms collapsing domestic currencies, but it is often overshadowed by foreign fiat currencies, international bonds, equities, and real estate. This contrasts sharply with Weimar Germany or Zimbabwe, where gold and foreign exchange were virtually the only lifelines. The difference lies in access: when citizens have access to international assets or hard foreign currency, those assets often outperform gold in both liquidity and long-term returns.

The broader synthesis is that gold is not always the best hedge against hyperinflation. It is a reliable insurance policy, but it is not growth-oriented and it is not always liquid. Its role is to preserve a baseline of wealth when fiat collapses, not to deliver superior returns compared to diversified, productive assets. In Brazil, the U.S. dollar, equities, and real estate outshone gold. In Russia, the dollar and international assets were superior. In Yugoslavia, the Deutsche Mark was king.

This does not mean gold is useless. Far from it. Gold played a critical role in all three cases as a last-resort store of value. Families who had no access to foreign currencies or international assets were still far better off holding gold than holding local fiat. But those with access to global diversification consistently did better. Gold's strength lies in its universality and independence from governments; its weakness lies in its lack of yield and its lower liquidity compared to foreign fiat.

The investment implication is clear: gold is best viewed as insurance within a diversified portfolio, not as a sole hedge. Hyperinflation proves this in both directions: in some cases, gold was the only effective hedge; in others, it was outperformed by foreign currencies and global assets. The prudent investor recognizes both sides of the story.

Equities and gold live at opposite ends of the financial spectrum: one is a claim on human enterprise and compounding profits; the other is an inert monetary metal whose power emerges primarily when trust in the system falters. That asymmetry is the through-line of two centuries of data. In tranquil decades when earnings grow and property rights are stable, equities dominate by harnessing retained profits and reinvested dividends. In panics and regime breaks, gold's lack of counterparty risk and low correlation become its superpower. The long record tells both truths at once, which is why the academic consensus places equities at the top of the long-run return table, with gold valuable—but not as a compounding engine.

The broadest, most frequently cited measurements come from the Dimson–Marsh–Staunton database, published annually in the UBS Global Investment Returns Yearbook. Over 1900–2023, global equities earn roughly 5% real per year, global bonds about 2%, and bills under 1%; gold, once it floated post-1971, sits closer to ~2–3% real with high volatility and low correlation to financial assets. This is a simple but brutal hierarchy: stocks create wealth, bonds preserve some purchasing power with income, bills/cash trail inflation, and gold—while sometimes spectacular in crises—does not match the long-run compounding of ownership in businesses.

The U.S. has been an especially fertile ground for equity investors. Jeremy Siegel's Stocks for the Long Run aggregates two centuries of returns and puts the real annual return of U.S. stocks around 6½–7%. To translate that: $1 invested in U.S. equities in the early 1800s—dividends reinvested, costs ignored—compounds to an astronomical sum in real purchasing power, while $1 in gold inches forward by pennies over the same timeframe. The difference is dividends and retained earnings. Shares are productive rights on expanding cash flows; gold has no yield. That single structural difference, repeated for two centuries, dwarfs every short-run episode where gold dominates.

Yet the equity record is not a straight line; it is a jagged mountain range. Entire decades—think 1930s, 1970s, or 2000–2009—saw equities bleed or stall in real terms. This is precisely where gold sometimes writes its legend. But if we zoom back out to 50- or 100-year windows, equities' dividend reinvestment overwhelms the intermittent outperformance of gold. The Yearbook's global panels show this clearly: volatility for equities is high, but the payoff for bearing it is a structurally higher real return than any non-yielding asset can deliver.

Another hard truth from the equity literature is that most of the market's total wealth creation comes from a tiny minority of stocks. Bessembinder's analysis of every U.S. common stock since 1926 shows roughly 4% of names generate all the net wealth relative to T-bills; the median stock underperforms T-bills over its lifetime. This is a warning and an opportunity. It warns that concentrated stock picking is dangerous—most individual names disappoint. It also implies that broad indexing (or very diversified portfolios) give you exposure to the rare compounding monsters that drive the asset class's long-run superiority. Gold, by contrast, never morphs into a compounding monster; it simply sits, with episodic price surges and long plateaus.

Where does this leave a serious allocator weighing gold against equities? Start with the arithmetic. If you believe the Yearbook's global baseline—~5% real for equities—then an all-equity allocation is the most powerful engine of purchasing-power growth known in financial markets. But the engine stalls, sometimes for long periods, and it can implode when credit systems seize up. That's when gold's low correlation and no-default nature matter. The metal's post-1971 ~2–3% real is not trivial, and its flight-to-quality behavior helps limit portfolio drawdowns. The correct comparison, then, is not "gold or equities," but how much gold to hold alongside equities to trade some growth for resilience.

Consider also the sequence risk that haunts equity-heavy savers. Two investors with identical average returns can have wildly different outcomes if one suffers a deep early bear market. Gold has a history of zigging when equities zag in macro shocks (not every time, but often enough), which is why multi-asset studies find small gold sleeves can improve Sharpe ratios and reduce max drawdowns even though gold's standalone long-run return lags. In other words, gold's value to an equity investor is portfolio math, not raw CAGR bragging rights.

The 1970s remain the poster child for gold's usefulness against equities: U.S. CPI surged, real equity returns were poor, and gold exploded upward once it floated, turning $35 into hundreds per ounce. The reverse is equally instructive: the 1980–2001 interval saw gold's real price fall roughly 70–85%from peak to trough even as equities delivered handsome real returns. Over a full cycle, equities' growth engine wins; gold's episodic spikes are insurance payouts, not compounding.

Region matters. The Yearbook documents that global equities earn a bit less than U.S. equities over the 20th century because of devastating wars and confiscations in multiple markets. That reality strengthens, rather than weakens, the case for global equity diversification—own a broad slice of world profits so no single political regime can zero you out. Gold is a different hedge for a different risk: systemic monetary failure and inflation shocks. The two hedges—global diversification and some gold—are complementary, not substitutes.

A common rejoinder is that gold "keeps up with inflation" better than equities. The literature does notsupport that as a general statement. Erb & Harvey demonstrate that realized inflation explains surprisingly little of gold's long-horizon price changes; most variation is in the real gold price (i.e., sentiment/valuation). Equities, meanwhile, are claims on nominal GDP: revenues and earnings tend to rise with the price level over long spans. That's why equities have historically beaten inflation by a wide margin—not in every decade, but across centuries.

What about risk-adjusted terms? Over long windows, equities carry volatility in the high teens (similar to gold at times) but earn a much higher real return, giving them a superior Sharpe long-run. Gold's Sharpe tends to be near zero over very long periods, improving meaningfully only if you pick windows anchored on crises. That doesn't make gold useless; it makes it a tactical/structural diversifier rather than a primary growth asset. The Yearbook's portfolio tables underscore that 5–15% gold sleeves can raise portfolio Sharpe by cutting left-tail risk even as the blended CAGR dips slightly.

The equity concentration reality (Bessembinder) adds one more nuance. If a small handful of stocks generates the lion's share of long-run wealth, then missing those winners is catastrophic. Broad, low-cost indexing maximizes your odds of catching those tail winners. Gold cannot substitute for that exposure; it can only soften the blow if markets crater while you wait for compounding to resume. That's the rational frame: own equities for growth, own some gold for resilience.

Finally, it's worth stating the behavioral asymmetry plainly. In drawdowns, equity investors panic and sell low; gold holders panic and buy high. Both destroy returns. The academic evidence doesn't excuse bad behavior, but it does explain why portfolios that pre-commit to a small allocation of gold (or other diversifiers) often produce better realized results for real people than theoretical all-equity lines on a chart. The hedge you are willing to hold through a storm beats the "optimal" allocation you abandon at the first lightning strike. The Yearbook's century of data proves the math; the last few crises prove the psychology.

For most of modern financial history, bonds and bills/CDs have been the canonical "safe" assets: they pay a contractual income stream, sit higher in the capital structure than equity, and (in sovereign form) have traditionally been treated as risk-free in nominal terms. Gold is the anti-bond: no yield, no maturity, no issuer. That single structural difference—income vs. no income—ends up explaining the bulk of the long-run performance gap, the different ways they behave under inflation and deflation, and why portfolios typically reserve fundamentally different jobs for each.

Over very long spans, high-quality government bonds have delivered positive but modest real returns. In countries spared by default, wars, or confiscation, the average has been on the order of ~2% real per year across the 20th century; corporate bonds a touch higher due to credit premia. Those real returns, however, are highly regime-dependent. In deflationary or disinflationary eras (the interwar episodes outside of defaults; the Volcker disinflation from 1981 forward), bonds shine: coupons are fixed, prices rally when yields fall, and purchasing power rises as the general price level stagnates or declines. In high-inflation eras (the 1940s yield-cap period; the 1970s stagflation), bonds get crushed in real terms, sometimes catastrophically, because coupons lag the price level and market yields adjust upward only after painful price declines.

Gold inverts much of that pattern. In deflation, gold's nominal price may be fixed (historical pegs) or simply sluggish, but because the price level is falling, an ounce's purchasing power tends to rise—Jastram's classic finding. In inflation, gold often reprices upward—sometimes explosively—because its real price mean-reverts around a long-run "constant" while nominal prices chase the weakening currency. Where bonds are an income contract vulnerable to inflation, gold is a non-contract claimthat floats precisely when contracts are being repriced.

Those contrasts become concrete in the three most instructive U.S. regimes. In the 1940s, wartime yield caps held Treasury returns below inflation; bonds bled purchasing power while the official $35/oz peg damped gold's visible move domestically (though its true scarcity value still rose internationally). In the 1970s, as the dollar left Bretton Woods, gold launched from $35 to hundreds per ounce, while bonds delivered deeply negative real returns as inflation outpaced coupons. Then in the 1980s–1990s disinflation, the pendulum reversed: bonds enjoyed a multi-decade bull market as yields fell from the mid-teens to low single digits, producing equity-like total returns; gold endured a generational slump in both nominal and real terms.

Short-term bills and CDs are different again. They are the liquidity anchor of a portfolio—low duration, low volatility, and the ability to roll frequently at prevailing rates. Over long spans, however, cash-like instruments have barely kept up with inflation or modestly lagged it, depending on country and period. In the rare years when short rates soar above inflation, bills/CDs can deliver brief real gains, but structurally they are insurance for sequence risk and liquidity, not engines of real wealth creation. Gold usually beats cash over long horizons because cash's purchasing power erodes; but when monetary policy tightens and real short rates turn positive, cash can out-carry gold for long stretches.

A subtle but critical point is term structure. Bonds pay you a term premium for taking duration risk; bills don't. Gold has no term, so there's no built-in risk premium to harvest—only price variationaround a drifting real anchor. That's why bonds can compound in quiet decades while gold meanders: coupons reinvest, price gains accrue when yields fall, and the math of duration amplifies benign regimes. Gold, lacking carry, must earn its keep through revaluation in unstable regimes.

Credit adds another wrinkle. Investment-grade credit typically outperforms sovereigns over time (carry + modest default risk); high yield outperforms IG but with equity-like drawdowns. In inflationary spikes and recessions, spreads widen, and credit behaves more like equities. Gold's correlation stays low in those moments, which is precisely when a small gold sleeve can offset widening spreads in a bond-heavy book.

Finally, inflation-protected bonds (TIPS) deserve their own line. For investors who want explicit CPI linkage plus income, TIPS solve the precise problem that ruins nominal bonds in inflationary shocks. Historically, when measured on a risk-adjusted basis since their inception, TIPS have often compared favorably to gold as an inflation hedge in mild to moderate inflation, while gold takes the crown in tail-risk regimes where financial-system trust, real yields, and geopolitics move together. In other words: TIPS are the engineered inflation hedge; gold is the systemic one.

Bottom line: bonds/bills/CDs are for income, liability matching, and ballast; gold is for monetary regime insurance. Over a century, bonds compound modest real wealth; cash keeps you liquid; gold doesn't compound but pays off when contracts and currencies wobble.

Domestic cash is the purest safety in nominal terms and the most fragile in real terms. It eliminates mark-to-market risk but guarantees exposure to inflation. That's why in normal decades, cash is the worst long-run asset: convenience and liquidity are purchased with slow erosion of purchasing power. Gold, despite volatility, typically beats cash over long spans because it is not tethered to a coupon that can be silently taxed by inflation.

Crisis dynamics flip priorities. In bank runs, capital controls, or sudden devaluations, the most valuable asset is often foreign currency—the USD, EUR, or (historically) the Deutsche Mark—because it combines liquidity with stable purchasing power in cross-border trade. This is why, in several hyperinflations (Brazil late-80s/early-90s; Russia 1990s; Yugoslavia 1992–94), hard foreign moneybecame the de facto unit of account and the daily medium of exchange, while gold served as a store of value that had to be converted (with frictions) before spending. In other words: gold is savings; foreign currency is spending when domestic fiat collapses.

In non-crisis periods with positive real short rates, domestic cash/bills can be a surprisingly strong tactical competitor to gold: carry accumulates while gold faces opportunity cost. When real short rates are negative, the equation reverses—cash quietly bleeds, and gold has a macro tailwind.

The practical takeaway is to separate three jobs: local cash for expenses/emergency fund, hard foreign currency for extreme domestic stress, and gold for a non-sovereign store of value that sits outside the banking system entirely.

Across long samples, equities and gold often post similar headline volatilities (mid-teens annualized), but their Sharpe ratios diverge because equities' real returns are structurally higher. That pushes equities' long-run Sharpe into the ~0.3–0.4 range while gold's settles closer to ~0 over very long windows. Bonds show lower volatility and lower return; their Sharpe can rival equities during disinflationary eras, but collapses when inflation shocks hit. Bills/cash have tiny volatility and tiny real return; Sharpe can look okay in short, high-rate episodes, but over decades is rarely compelling.

Those summary ratios hide the main reason gold shows up in institutional policy portfolios: correlation. In "normal" expansions, gold's correlation to equities and bonds is low to mildly positive; in systemic stress, it tends to go negative vs. equities and positive vs. breakeven inflation, delivering crisis convexity. That is the diversification you cannot get from simply mixing stocks and bonds, because the stock-bond correlation itself is regime-dependent (negative in disinflationary demand shocks; positive in inflationary supply shocks). A gold sleeve equalizes the portfolio's behavior across these regimes.

Drawdowns tell the same story. A 60/40 portfolio's worst episodes often involve either (a) equity crashes with falling inflation (when bonds help), or (b) inflation shocks where stocks and bonds sell off together. Gold tends to soften both tails: it can rally when equities crater (flight-to-quality), and it often rallies (or at least holds) when inflation drives bond losses. That asymmetric help—left-tail protection—is why small allocations raise realized Sortino ratios (penalizing downside only) even if Sharpe doesn't leap.

None of this rescues gold's standalone profile. On its own, it is a volatile, non-yielding asset with long flat spells and sharp cycles. But in a system portfolio, it improves resilience, which is how real investors survive long enough to harvest equities' compounding.

When the returns of gold, equities, bonds, and cash are laid side by side over centuries, the hierarchy is remarkably consistent. Equities dominate in compounded real returns because they are ownership claims on productive enterprise. Bonds provide moderate real returns with income but are vulnerable to inflationary regimes. Bills and cash/CDs preserve nominal value but usually erode in real terms. Gold oscillates around constancy in real purchasing power, spiking in crises but delivering very low or near-zero average real returns outside those regimes. The result is that gold's role is not to win the long race, but to make sure investors survive the sharp turns.

The UBS Global Investment Returns Yearbook provides the most rigorous evidence across 23 countries since 1900. Globally, equities have delivered about 5.3% real per year, bonds around 1.9%, and bills around 0.8%. Gold, measured since the 1970s free float, averages 2–3% real but with volatility often as high as or higher than equities. This gap in compounding is immense: a $1 allocation to global equities in 1900 grows to hundreds of dollars in real terms by the 2020s; the same dollar in gold, measured post-1971, barely breaks into double digits in real terms.

For the U.S., Jeremy Siegel's Stocks for the Long Run gives an even starker contrast. From 1802 to the present, U.S. equities returned 6½–7% real annually, compared to gold's ~0–1%. That means $1 in stocks compounds to nearly a million dollars of real purchasing power across two centuries, while $1 in gold preserves about a dollar or two. This isn't an indictment of gold's usefulness—it simply reflects that gold is inert, while equities capture human productivity and innovation.

The studies also confirm that gold has a tendency to shine precisely when equities and bonds stumble together. The 1970s stagflation and the 2008 financial crisis are textbook examples: in both, diversified equity/bond portfolios suffered, while gold delivered positive returns. But the inverse is equally important: gold's 1980–2001 slump, when real prices fell 70–85%, shows that long flat spells are common and devastating for compounding. Equities, despite volatility, powered ahead during that same period.

A crucial detail often overlooked is volatility and drawdown. Annualized volatility for equities typically sits around 15–20%, while gold's is similar or even slightly higher. That means gold is not the "low risk" asset it is sometimes marketed as. Yet the correlation profile is different: equities and bonds sometimes correlate positively (inflationary shocks), sometimes negatively (disinflationary recessions), but gold's correlation is structurally low and often turns negative in crises. This is the diversification dividend gold brings: not less volatility per se, but different volatility that softens a portfolio's worst moments.

Long-term bond and cash comparisons reinforce gold's place as an inflation hedge of last resort. Nominal bonds deliver income, but their Achilles' heel is inflation. Bills and CDs provide liquidity, but inflation grinds them down slowly. Gold offers no yield, but in extreme inflationary shocks it tends to reprice upward rapidly. The Deutsche Bank Long-Term Asset Return Study finds that in periods of CPI >5%, gold's excess return over bonds averages +3% per year, underscoring its conditional utility.

The Bessembinder study on equities adds another nuance. Since only ~4% of stocks create all the net wealth in U.S. markets, diversified exposure to equities is essential; missing those winners is catastrophic. Gold cannot replace that equity engine, but it can ensure that an investor's portfolio does not implode during the crises that often tempt people to abandon equities before the winners do their work.

Cash comparisons highlight the same trade-off. In normal decades, gold trounces cash in real terms; cash's purchasing power is steadily eroded. But in acute domestic crises, foreign cash—dollars in Brazil, Deutsche Marks in Yugoslavia, dollars in Russia—outperformed gold for day-to-day survival because of its liquidity. That's why the synthesis is never "gold instead of cash," but "cash for liquidity, foreign cash for crisis spending, and gold for long-term off-system savings."

Finally, risk-adjusted returns seal the picture. Equities boast the highest long-run Sharpe ratios (≈0.3–0.4) because they deliver strong real returns for their volatility. Bonds' Sharpe ratios vary by regime: strong in disinflation, terrible in inflation. Gold's Sharpe ratio is close to zero over very long samples, improving only when measured across inflationary decades or crisis windows. Bills and cash show weak Sharpe ratios except in short-lived high-rate episodes. The portfolio implication is therefore consistent across studies: gold improves downside protection and diversification, but it cannot replace equities or even bonds as compounding engines
 
Last edited:

Similar threads

DarkRange55
Replies
0
Views
41
Offtopic
DarkRange55
DarkRange55
DarkRange55
Replies
0
Views
31
Offtopic
DarkRange55
DarkRange55
DarkRange55
Replies
0
Views
33
Offtopic
DarkRange55
DarkRange55
DarkRange55
Replies
1
Views
41
Offtopic
MatiSendiri
M
DarkRange55
Replies
5
Views
101
Offtopic
DarkRange55
DarkRange55